As previously
noted in this space, much grander and more substantive reform had been
offered up by the Gov. Bobby
Jindal Administration. But after predictable resistance from the civil
service, watered-down alterations got enacted, and in the first year of full
use, in terms of statistics, the almost perfect qualified rate remained
essentially unchanged, with almost no requests to fire people for low
performance.
Schroder commented, “Why do
evaluations if everyone is going to come out with flying colors? I’m not
persuaded that almost every single employee is doing a great job.” By contrast,
Director of State Civil Service Shannon Templet said they must be, for two
reasons: the new protocols were more than before evaluative of tasks and that
the proportion of those employees rated qualified was not significantly higher
than what was found in the private sector.
Both her arguments supporting the
validity of the scores as truly measuring quality, if not made disingenuously,
then are too simplistic. The increased emphasis on task evaluation presupposes
that the standards of task performance themselves represent adequately rigorous
expectations of employees. That we saw some agencies give as many as a third of
all employees the highest rating while at least one gave this to none
illustrates widely divergent expectations in this regard, as chance would
suggest almost never would distributions of performance go to such extremes.
This has been the flaw from the start of the system before and after its tepid reform,
and left unaddressed sabotages the validity of any evaluation system.
And the comparison to the private
sector misleads by its apples to oranges nature. For one thing, the separation
rate (voluntarily leaving) is twice
as high in the private sector than public sector, meaning that many fewer
government employees leave for reasons good and bad, or that there are fewer
good employees in the public sector that have a chance to do better elsewhere
and that in it forcing out inferior employees, which then presumably erodes the
bottom part of the performance distribution that could explain its upward skew,
does not happen all that often. And the national low turnover rate through
firings in the private sector is five
times that of the miniscule rate in the federal public sector, underscoring
the difficulty in discharging for cause public sector employees because of
civil service protections. That the average
tenure of government employees is twice that of those in the private sector
corroborates these inferences by showing that worse-performing employees can
hang on to their jobs where they could not in the private sector and that there
are fewer better-performing employees that have the ability to move on than in
the private sector.
In other words, were the factors –
fewer superior employees to begin with, more inferior ones – accurately reflected
in an evaluation regime, we should expect to see the rate of qualified
employees, instead of being slightly higher in Louisiana’s bureaucracy than in
the privates sector – should be significantly lower. If anything, unless one
unrealistically believes there’s some magic that just makes Louisiana’s
bureaucrats unusually better than the norm, this comparison demonstrates not
the validity of the present measurement process, but its invalidity.
Again, this leads back to the
evaluative process itself and the doubts that it is done in a fashion that is
rigorous enough, certainly not standardized in application. If Schroder and
other policy-makers want to investigate this, they should pass a study resolution
to commission a consultant to study the standards, comparing the task
expectations of each task in a job (comparing job to job wouldn’t work because of
the substantial variety and differences between them in the sectors, and that
some public sector jobs really have no comparable positions in the private
sector) for each sector. Chances are expectations are lower in Louisiana’s
public sector, and so reforms would have to occur that would raise these.
Do that, and likely the state’s
bureaucracy separation and turnover rates would increase and tenure decrease to
closer to private sector rates. Better, spurred by this state employees should
become more productive – especially given that their total compensation almost
certainly exceeds that of those in the private sector with comparable job tasks
– saving taxpayers money and providing improved service delivery.
Schroder is correct to question
these results. He and other policy-makers should take the next step by authorizing
delving into this matter in greater detail, and follow up with legislation if
necessary to make corrections.
No comments:
Post a Comment