Like herpes, the Patient Protection and (Un)Affordable Care Act, known derisively as “Obamacare,” is the gift that keeps on giving, this time threatening to bring additional injury to Louisiana taxpayers over salary payments to teachers.
Because of the law’s provision that
any non-small organization offer and subsidize health care insurance to
employees of at least 30 hours a week or pay a $2,000 fine for each, either way
this would cause a substantial increase in costs. Thus, many
school districts across the state are reducing the number of hours a substitute
may teach, for generally after three days a week of substitute teaching
another day would bump them over the limit. In turn, this is reducing the
amount of available hours from the existing pool of substitutes, leading in
many places to a shortage of instructors.
In response, one affected
superintendent conjectured that an increase in the amount a retired teacher
could gain in salary as a substitute from 25 to 50 percent of pension income,
set by state law, could alleviate the bottleneck. Except for positions of critical
shortage that do not have to follow this standard, the cap prevents teachers
from retiring and then double-dipping to any large extent, but by relaxing this
requirement, theoretically as substitutes they could double their hours (and
for those that would go over 30 hours as a result, insuring them should be moot
as they already would have as part of post-employment benefits, largely paid by
the state) and take up the slack now thrust upon districts by Obamacare.
But this is a bad idea. Already,
teachers get a pretty sweet
deal in pension benefits. The average classroom teacher’s salary in
Louisiana (as of fiscal
year 2012) already is over $48,000 a year, and the typical salary
of one with a bachelor’s degree only and 25 years in is more like $50,000. (Keep in mind they also only work typically 182 days a year.) Stay
years longer, and the typical salary (that was subject to almost automatic
“merit” raises every year until reforms recently were instituted) will have
increased tens of thousands of dollars on top of that, creating a lucrative
base on which to derive a pension.
Yet many teachers will retire with
higher pay than even this, because some will pursue graduate degrees and
certification that increase base compensation, and because many strive to stay
at least 30 years, given they can retire with a pension at any age with that
and that would be 75 percent of the average of their salary typically from
their last three years of service (recent reforms have changed this, but those
hired under those rules are many years removed from retiring and getting a
pension). Retirement at only 20 years also is possible for this cohort, at
about 60 percent reduction, or at 25 years being at least age 55. The maximum
100 percent pension occurs after 40 years of service.
In other words, with a bachelor’s
degree one could retire at 42 and draw a pension at about 20 percent of the
highest salary earned, or at 52 draw 75 percent, or at 62 draw 100 percent.
Then one can turn right back around and through substitute teaching get up to
25 percent of that pension income, meaning in essence the 52-year-old could
make 100 percent of last salary by working perhaps half-time (as substitute
rates, fixed per day but which vary by district, could be less than half of
what a regular teacher would get per day, also depending on that salary), and
the 62-year-old 125 percent. Few pension arrangements in the private sector are
this generous in both terms of age and payment. The recommended change would add
yet another 25 percent bonus.
Which is why changing the standard
would serve as bad public policy. This not only would encourage earlier
retirements, which would thin the pool of full-time teachers, and with this
thinning of supply pushing salaries even higher to keep people from retiring
earlier who intend to supplement through serving as substitutes, but also would
create an incentive for those not intending to substitute teach upon retirement
to retire in the others’ places because the higher salary makes for a higher
pension, creating a vicious cycle either of tolerating shortages or of
ever-increasing wages. It doesn’t solve the problem
Subsidizing a reduced work schedule,
which only will increase costs to taxpayers both at the state level and for
many at the local level (where many districts add their own funds to their
share from the state for salaries), misses the real issue. The problem is with
this specific provision of Obamacare, one of many of its odious features, that
all together increase health care costs while making for less efficient, if not
lower quality, delivery of health care services.
One of the insidious principles
behind Obamacare, as exemplified through the employer fee or individual mandate
for those without employer-provided insurance, is to make people pay for it to
achieve its ideological objectives of greater government control and
redistribution of wealth to favored constituencies. Increasing pay to teacher
retirees penalizes further the citizenry because of it, when the genuine
solution is to get rid of it or at least excise its (which comprise a majority
of the program in total) objectionable provisions. Taxpayers should not be
asked to let the power elite behind Obamacare get off the hook; continued
school administrative difficulties because of this law creates incentives to
demand undeniably necessary corrective actions to it. Citizens should not pay
for a problem easily eliminated, so legislators should not raise the current 25
percent standard.
No comments:
Post a Comment