This doesn’t refer to improved horology,
better chocolatiers, or increased viniculture, but instead to imposing a double
requirement on passage of any tax measure requiring voter approval. SB
200 by state Sen. Bret Allain
would require that not only a majority of those voting in the election approve
of the measure for it to pass into law, but also that a minimum of 20 percent
of registered voters in the jurisdiction turn out for the election.
In local elections for these
matters in the state, it is not surprising to have turnout
figures of five percent or even less, even
in large jurisdictions. This has spurred calls that important fiscal
decisions end up getting decided with the explicit support of perhaps two
percent of all voters mocks the concept of majority rule. Worse, low turnouts
for elections with only tax measures on the ballot, as permitted in the regular
election cycle by providing additional dates beyond those when elections for
office are scheduled, can be used by governments to increase chances for
passing of these tax measures that they depend upon for revenues. The thinking
here is that low interest allows those who do or would disproportionately
benefit from these taxes – bureaucrats, politicians, recipients of government
contracts, etc. – to have every incentive to mobilize to vote for the tax,
while to the general public paying of these taxes (hidden in sales
transactions, rental payments, mortgage bills, etc.) these seem out of sight
and mind and so it is much harder to mobilize those against these to come to
the polls and cast negative votes.
Thus, Allain’s bill would count a
no-show on election day as an automatic no vote for the 20 percent hurdle. Which
has the above beneficiaries – having benefits concentrated among a few but paid
for per person in smaller amounts by the many – and ideological advocates of
big government complaining about the bill’s requirement, making various
spurious claims designed to defeat the effort.
One red herring is that this will
doom all tax measures to defeat. While it’s true that it’s rare that tax issues
on a ballot without any elective office or even any other kind of ballot issue accompanying
seldom reach 20 percent turnout, some do, such as the Apr. 30. 2011 fire protection
millage vote in Jefferson Parish that almost got a third of electors out. But
more relevantly, tax measures often go well above the mark when there are other
items on the ballot. So if there’s fear that voter disinterest would impose a
structural disincentive against tax approval, then it’s a simple matter of scheduling
these items when other elections encourage greater voter interest in these tax
matters – where a change that produces greater citizen interest in public
policy and self-governing only can be considered beneficial to the workings of
democracy.
However, a half-baked objection
to scheduling tax elections when there are other items on the ballot would be
that what if the tax is needed to be decided upon and no such other things loom
for deciding in the immediate future? This ignores the fact that in a quadrennial
cycle three of those years will have regularly scheduled federal, state, and local
officer elections, and in some jurisdictions like Bossier City or Gretna in all
four years. For existing taxes, it’s known years in advance when they will
expire and so a renewal easily can be planned around known dates of officer
elections, and it’s unlikely enough offices would be uncontested to leave few
incentives to participate. Plus, the option of using the other dates now
normally used by taxing authorities still remains. And, just in case an
emergency does come up where policy-makers think taxes are so necessary, R.S. 18:402 provides for
using almost any additional Saturday for these elections in a pinch and R.S. 18:1283
allows a quarter of electors to call such an election, and if they are in fact so
necessary undoubtedly at least a fifth of the electorate will participate.
Finally, a straw man argument is
that only those who bother to turn out to vote should have a say in the
ultimate decision. But that is a far less compelling reasoning than in
reference to elections with candidates. With the latter, voters chose to have
someone stand in for them for a term to make policy decisions, where nonvoting
may be interpreted as satisfaction, or at least a willingness to accept
consequences thereof by failing to vote, with at least once candidate running.
Moreover, the winners must pay attention to nonvoters as well as voters in
their election when making their policy choices, in order to maximize their chances
at reelection if not because they feel they should represent all. Thus,
elections are just one means by which to influence on a certain policy. Yet in
the case of a tax item, that is just one discrete decision where there is no
delegation of authority to decide on behalf of the nonvoter and only one shot
to influence. When asking citizens to decide on upon one issue of policy
directly, government should attempt to maximize registered voter turnout as
much as possible to ensure greater democratic integrity.
Especially when it can be done
not just for free, but actually with cost savings. By creating an incentive for
authorities to schedule optional tax elections on dates with officer elections
that must be held regardless (except in the highly unlikely scenario where all
officers have unopposed candidates), this negates the need to have to pay extra
expenses in holding tax elections on their own dedicated days. Election activity
on these days may be dispensed with while tax elections still get held,
promoting efficient use of taxpayer resources.
And, this practice is not
uncommon in the rest of the democratic world. For national referenda, the
aforementioned Alpine countries, among others, have an even stricter standard
that requires a double majority, of both proportion of registered voters and
those who vote with approval, in order to put a measure onto their books. Many
still succeed, so it seems not to create an insurmountable barrier to making
policy both widely vetted and popular. Other American states also have implemented similar requirements to this bill.
Recognize that fear of losing
revenues to support their jobs or activities by direct beneficiaries of taxes
and of smaller, less powerful government by ideological fans of big government drives
opposition to this bill, in that it would be less likely they could access the structural advantage in these matters they now enjoy. Regardless, SB 200
makes all the sense in the world in that it will not affect the ability to
impose taxes truly necessary and desired by the public, and probably will cost
taxpayers less in the process, all the while promoting democratic governance,
thus meriting its becoming law.
1 comment:
BRAVO, Senator Allain!!!
Post a Comment