Jeffrey D. Sadow is an associate professor of political science at Louisiana State University Shreveport. If you're an elected official, political operative or anyone else upset at his views, don't go bothering LSUS or LSU System officials about that because these are his own views solely. This publishes five days weekly with the exception of 7 holidays. Also check out his Louisiana Legislature Log especially during legislative sessions (in "Louisiana Politics Blog Roll" below).
Search This Blog
24.1.17
Convention unnecessary to fix LA fiscal problems
Although some, principal among them Gov. John Bel Edwards, think
a constitutional convention in order for Louisiana, conditions simply don’t
warrant that.
Certainly, the fiscal straitjacket into which
Louisiana has amended and legislated itself needs unbinding. Almost seven
out of every eight dollars generated by the state by law or the
Constitution go to a specified purpose (which includes self-generated revenues
such as user fees and tuition at state institutions of higher learning). Most
of the remainder ends up funding higher education, health care, or corrections.
This hyper-inflexibility hampers budgeting and makes past a certain point addressing
mid-year budget deficits almost impossible.
Those arguing for a convention believe this as the
best way to sweep aside locked-in spending. By loosening dedications and protections
of funds that receive these proceeds, better matching of money to need could
happen, rather than enduring government-on-autopilot.
But three things work against the calling of a
convention for this purpose. First, the vast majority of the 370
dedications come from statute; the Constitution bakes in only around two
dozen. To fix these needs no alteration to the Constitution at all, just political
willpower.
Second, even with relatively few constitutional
dedications, much of the directed spending occurs because of these. For example,
about two-thirds
of all general fund revenue gets shuttled to nondiscretionary purposes. In
all, the 26 accounts suck in just over half of all dedicated monies.
Further, the largest of these address areas often
considered crucial and/or underfunded. For example, the single largest in terms
of dollars going in and out is the Transportation Trust Fund, recently in the
area of $1.4 billion annually. Yet rather than redirect away from this,
policy-makers have taken to calling for an increase into it, as of late wishing
to jack up the revenues going to it by 50
percent through more than doubling the gasoline tax through an increase of
23 cents per gallon.
In other words, should a consensus build to pare
or eliminate certain less-crucial dedications, it would not take a
constitutional convention to do so. This would involve relatively few items.
Nor would changing the rules by which policy-makers could make cuts mid-year
need an entire convention to accomplish.
Neither would reform in this fashion require
interconnectivity among the discrete changes. One argument for a convention
maintains that that special interests, with different coalitions forming around
each separate item, collectively could block alterations, but if everything
hung together in a series of tradeoffs aimed at overall simplification and
flexibility that special interests could feel assured that, if they ended up losers,
other compensations would soften the blow and thereby make them less likely to
coalesce to defeat individual items.
However, if merely unlocking several dedications
and loosening strictures on deficit reduction, proponents reasonably can
publicize (to the electorate that would have to produce majority votes in favor
of amendments spelling out these) funding reductions won’t necessarily happen
by this and that policy-makers could respond better to sustaining areas most
vulnerable under the current system. The benefits of connectivity generally get
overplayed and the drawbacks to separated items overemphasized.
Third, recent past conventions give guidance that
existing policy-makers have too much influence with a convention. Even as most
of those to the 1973 version faced election to get there, most of the elected
already held some kind of elective office, and the appointees largely were
allies of their appointer, the governor. In 1992, legislators made themselves the
convention, along with extra pay to do so. Their limited product (only dealing
with fiscal matters) voters
summarily rejected – the centerpiece of which being a loosening of
dedicated funds in the procedure for tackling deficits.
Given these reasons, while discussion of fiscal
reforms requiring constitutional changes should commence with due haste, this
does not need a constitutional convention to succeed.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment