Running some numbers from various sources, he
argued that all the conflict over whether to increase taxes, how, and by how
much actually didn’t amount to a whole lot for the typical households. Best he figured,
whether on income or sales, it amounted to one percent of an individual’s
income.
That implies that all of the conflict renting the
session overdramatizes the situation. If just this amount, the tone of the article
asks, why can’t some agreement to hike taxes be reached?
If interpreted this way, that relies upon some very questionable assumptions, beginning with the one percent characterization as something essentially trivial. That baldly misses the point that, for some households, one percent might serve as a tipping point between affording necessities or funding activities, such as furthering education, that might provide a substantial boost to the family’s fortunes. More alarmingly, it completely ignores the normative argument involved: is it right that government takes more of what people earn, regardless of the size?
Answering that query shunted aside depends upon whether
the state already spends its existing revenues in an efficient manner and
whether everything on which it spends truly deserves backing by taxpayer
dollars. The evidence suggests neither is the case.
For example, why must the state
spend $200 million needlessly on caring for people with disabilities by
placing them in nursing homes rather than in the community? And, should the state
really spend
$150-$180 million a year to make movies when all studies show these
expenditures have such a high negative return?
You cannot remove these questions from consideration
of how much and who pays, if anybody, with a round of tax increases. It also
moots another talking point favored by money-grabbers that has proven the most
divisive issue of the session: the demand that increases come from income
rather than consumption taxes.
That rests upon the notion of regressivity, or
that as incomes go lower a higher proportion of that income gets taken by a
tax. Consumption taxes like sales taxes feature regressivity, while an income
tax, if marginal rates increase as do incomes, can be shaped as the opposite,
progressive in nature.
While regressivity prompts leftists to whine about
how systems more reliant on sales taxes are “unfair,” the data show the
opposite. If there’s anything “unfair” about the present Louisiana taxation
regime, it comes from the fact that (in fiscal year 2016)
income tax filers of $100,000 and greater (adjusted gross) income, who comprise about one-eighth
of all filers, pay over three-fifths of all income taxes. Meanwhile, those who
made $30,000 or fewer, just over half of all filers, paid a whopping six
percent of total income taxes. Obviously, the remaining filers, 36 percent of
the total, paid the other third.
So, in this debate, Bridges brings up the wrong
question. Asking why can’t parties come to an agreement to lift from people’s
wallets apparently only a pittance acts as if the larger, more fundamental questions
don’t exist of whether Louisianans face enough taxation and how wisely their
state spends what it already takes.
Failure to do so puts the cart before the horse.
So, while the piece presents an interesting bit of trivia, it adds nothing
useful to discussions about Louisiana’s tax policy.
No comments:
Post a Comment